Abstract
Urban scaling analysis, the study of how aggregated urban features vary with the population of an urban area, provides a promising framework for discovering commonalities across cities and uncovering dynamics shared by cities across time and space. Here, we use the urban scaling framework to study an important, but under-explored feature in this community—income inequality. We propose a new method to study the scaling of income distributions by analysing total income scaling in population percentiles. We show that income in the least wealthy decile (10%) scales close to linearly with city population, while income in the most wealthy decile scale with a significantly superlinear exponent. In contrast to the superlinear scaling of total income with city population, this decile scaling illustrates that the benefits of larger cities are increasingly unequally distributed. For the poorest income deciles, cities have no positive effect over the null expectation of a linear increase. We repeat our analysis after adjusting income by housing cost, and find similar results. We then further analyse the shapes of income distributions. First, we find that mean, variance, skewness and kurtosis of income distributions all increase with city size. Second, the Kullback–Leibler divergence between a city’s income distribution and that of the largest city decreases with city population, suggesting the overall shape of income distribution shifts with city population. As most urban scaling theories consider densifying interactions within cities as the fundamental process leading to the superlinear increase of many features, our results suggest this effect is only seen in the upper deciles of the cities. Our finding encourages future work to consider heterogeneous models of interactions to form a more coherent understanding of urban scaling.
1. Introduction
Throughout human history, the global urban population has grown continuously. More than half of the global population is currently urbanized, placing cities at the centre of human development [1]. It is estimated that by 2030, the number of megacities, cities with more than 10 million inhabitants, will increase from 10 to approximately 40 [1]. Thus, there is an urgent need for a quantitative and predictive theory for how larger urban areas affect a wide variety of city features, dynamics and outcomes [2,3]. Perhaps most critically, we need this theory to address how larger cities positively and negatively affect socioeconomic outcomes and the quality of life of individuals.
Previous research has demonstrated power-law-like relationships between urban population (also referred to as size later in the text) and many urban features such as GDP, patents, crime and contagious diseases that persist globally [4–8]. These relationships can often be described by
One important aspect of urban features that remains under-explored in the urban scaling framework is economic inequality. Inequality has fundamental implications for individuals’ quality of life and the productivity and stability of societies [11]. Past research has heightened debate about economic inequality and its relationship with economic growth and general welfare [12–18]. Many have raised concern of its negative effects on political stability [12,19], crime [20] and corruption [21]. It has been shown that more unequal places have higher murder rates, grow more slowly, and the correlation between area-level inequality and population growth is positive [22]. Economic inequality is usually measured in terms of the dispersion in the distribution of income or wealth, such as in the Gini coefficient. Some past research has noted larger cities are correlated with increasing Gini coefficient in income distribution [23–25], but it remains unclear if there are systematic relationships between other features of the income distributions and urban area size. Furthermore, characterizing distributions by a single metric may lose important information [12]—for example, does being poor in bigger cities correspond to a higher or lower standard of living than being poor in a smaller city?
A few recent studies [26,27] have investigated the scaling of total income in various income brackets in Australia. These studies find that the total income in lower income brackets scales sublinearly or linearly, while higher brackets scale superlinearly, suggesting greater income agglomeration in the higher income categories in more populated cities. While these studies are informative and provide a new measure for inequality in terms of absolute income (instead of relative income, as in the Gini coefficient), a limitation is that this measure confounds inequality with average income, which increases with city population. In particular, the ‘equal’ situation in this new measure of inequality is when the total income for all income brackets scales linearly. However, given that total income scales superlinearly in cities globally [4,5], this ‘equal’ situation is unlikely to occur. For example, even if the shapes of income distributions remain identical, income bracket aggregations follow distinct scaling relationships as a result of differences in mean. Figure 1a,c illustrates this behaviour using simulated log-normal distributions. While the measure of inequality proposed in [26,27] can be valuable for some applications, it would be useful to untangle the increase in mean from the greater dispersion in income.
In this manuscript, we address a few keys questions: (1) how does income inequality (adjusted for shifting average income) systematically change with city size? (2) How different is the income of rich and poor people (measured by percentiles of the population) in small and large cities, and how does this difference scale with city size? (3) Are poor people in a larger city better off than poor people in a small city, after adjusting by the cost of living? How about the same for rich people?
Here, we propose a new method to study the scaling of inequality by analysing total income scaling in population percentiles. We show that income in the least wealthy decile (10%) scales almost linearly with city size, while that in the most wealthy decile scales with a significantly superlinear exponent. This illustrates that the benefits of larger cities are increasingly unequally distributed, and for the poorest income deciles, city growth has no positive effect on income growth over the null expectation of a linear increase. We find that these results hold after adjusting for cost of living as proxied by housing cost. We then introduce systematic considerations of the entire distribution of income to show which income distribution features are changing with city size. We find that the mean, variance, skewness and kurtosis of the income distribution all scale systematically with city size. We introduce a KL-divergence procedure to systematically compare all moments and find that comparisons with the largest cities also demonstrate a systematic scaling with city size, indicating that the overall shape of income distribution is radically shifting with city size. Finally, we discuss how these observations can be connected with the proposed mechanisms underlying urban scaling.
2. Data and methods
2.1. Data and income distribution estimation
The primary dataset used in our analysis is the 2015 American Community Survey conducted by the US Census Bureau (see electronic supplementary material for more detail). We use the income data reported on the level of census tracts, small local areas of on average 4500 people, of which on average 2300 reported income. In order to aggregate census tracts into cities, we gather the geographical definitions of urban areas from the United States Office of Management and Budget, which include Metropolitan Statistical Areas and Micropolitan Statistical Areas. We perform a spatial join between urban area outlines and census tract outlines. All census tracts which intersect a given urban area are assigned to that urban area. Census tracts which intersect multiple urban areas are assigned to both. The population of an urban area is defined as the sum of their census tracts’ populations. In our study sample, we analyse urban areas (also referred to as cities) with a population greater than 100 000.
We infer the individual-level income distribution in cities by applying the Gaussian kernel density estimator with a widened Silverman bandwidth function on the census-tract-level data. This method assumes income in each census tract is distributed as a Gaussian. The mean equals the average income of the census tract, and the standard deviation is calculated as a function of the number of data points. Aggregating the Gaussian probability density functions (PDFs) for each census tract in the city produces an estimated income PDF for the city. Examples of the estimated individual-level income distribution for a few cities are shown in figure 2.
2.2. Analysis of income scaling in deciles
We propose a new method to investigate the scaling of income aggregated by deciles in each city (i.e. the bottom 10%, the next 10% and so on). The number of individuals in decile n of city i is, , where Ni is the population of city i.
The total income in decile n of city i, is,
Figure 1c,d illustrates this method on simulated log-normal income distributions. Panel c represents the situation in which cities shift in log-mean with city size, but do not shift in log-standard deviation, and panel d represents the situation in which cities increase both log-mean and log-standard deviations with city size. We consider the former case an example of the ‘equal’ situation, and this method should lead to no variation in scaling exponents across deciles. Variations in scaling exponent only occur for the latter case. We also contrast the results of our method with that of the grouping by income bracket method in figure 1a,c, where variations in scaling exponents occur for both scenarios.
We group the data of income distributions of each city into deciles: the 10% of the population which reports the lowest income is grouped into the first decile (decile 1), and likewise for all 10 deciles up to the 10% of the population which has the highest income (decile 10). We then estimate the scaling exponent of total income for all deciles. We estimate the scaling exponent, β, and corresponding confidence intervals, by performing an ordinary least square regression of the log-transformed variables, , and β and c are the fitted parameters. This methodology is consistent with previous research such as [4].
2.3. Adjusting income by housing cost
In order to normalize income by the cost of living, we calculate total housing cost in a census tract as cost = 12 (urent r + uown o), where the average monthly rent r, the average monthly owner costs o, and the number of units of each type urent and uown are all taken from the 2015 American Community Survey (see electronic supplementary material for more detail and access information). We then repeat the decile-grouped analysis on income adjusted for housing cost, as well as analyse how the proportion of income spent on housing varies with city size in each decile.
2.4. Analysis of distributions
We further analyse how the shapes of the income distributions vary with city population. We first compute the first four statistical moments, mean, variance, skewness and kurtosis, for income distributions of each city, and analyse how they vary with population. We then compute the Kullback–Leibler (KL) divergence between each city’s income distribution and that of the largest city (New York–Newark–Jersey City area). The KL divergence measures how different one distribution is from another, while the zero value indicates the two distributions are identical, and a greater value indicates more divergence. Mathematically, the KL divergence between two discrete distributions of random variable x, P(x) and Q(x) is,
3. Results
3.1. Scaling of income in deciles
The results for scaling of income aggregated in deciles are summarized in figure 3. For the lowest two deciles, the scaling exponent β is linear or slightly sublinear (0.97). For upper deciles, β is consistently superlinear, as high as 1.16 when compared with the scaling exponent of total income in our dataset, β = 1.07. This shows that scaling effects are not equivalent for all segments of the population. The poorest two deciles in bigger cities make about the same income as their counterparts in smaller cities, while the wealthiest eight deciles in bigger cities make more than their counterparts in smaller cities, where the difference increases with the decile.
3.2. Scaling of decile income adjusted by housing cost
While the differences in income scaling that we have identified are important, they are not necessarily grounded in differences in the experiences of urban residents—cost of living can vary drastically across and within US cities, and if cost of living is changing in the exact same way as income, differences in income scaling between groups begin to lose meaning. In order to understand whether the differences in income scaling we see between deciles create differences in affordability and purchasing power, we look at changes in housing cost with city size.
We find that aggregate housing cost scales faster than aggregate income for every decile, implying that while income per person increases with city size, larger cities may still be overall less affordable. This difference is more dramatic for the poorer deciles—in the bottom decile, housing cost scales with β = 1.11 while income scales with β = 1.01; in the top decile, housing cost scales with β = 1.29 while income scales with β = 1.27. This is visualized in figure 4a—income exponents begin to catch up to housing cost exponents in richer deciles, but income exponents are never as high as housing cost exponents. Perhaps more intuitively, in figure 4b, we can see that the ratio between total housing cost and total income grows with city size for every decile, but more dramatically for poorer deciles. Together, these results imply a widening gap between richer and poorer residents in affordability of cities with city size.
3.3. Analysis of income distribution characteristics
We further analyse how income distributions vary with urban area population by studying the statistical moments of the income distributions. We first examine the first four moments: mean, variance, skewness and kurtosis.
The scaling of the four moments of the estimated individual income distribution for all cities in our data is shown in figure 5. The first moment, the mean, shows the well-characterized urban agglomeration effect: per capita income increases with city size [4]. The second, and third moments both increase similarly with city population, suggesting a widening of the distribution and increasing asymmetry with greater urban population. This can also be qualitatively observed in the example distributions in figure 2. Lastly, the kurtosis also increases with population size, showing an increasingly heavy tail with greater urban population.
We find a stronger relationship for higher statistical moments, indicating that for larger American cities, there is a more evident increase in the third and fourth moments. This means that there is a stronger increase in the growing tail of the distribution, in comparison to the first two statistical moments. This gives us an interesting indication of the distribution of economic benefits.
Another useful perspective on the scaling of the income distributions is to compare large and small cities using measures that consider the entire distribution through the KL divergence. Figure 6 shows the KL divergence between each US city and the largest city, as a function of the log-transformed city population. The KL divergence, in general, decreases with increasing city population, and approaches zero as the population approaches that of the largest city. This behaviour suggests that as cities get smaller, their income distributions are increasingly dissimilar to that of the largest city. The Pearson correlation between the two variables in figure 6 is −0.259, while the Spearman correlation is −0.718. The Pearson correlation measures the linear correlation between two variables, while the Spearman correlation measures the rank correlation, and assesses how well the relationship between two variables can be described by a monotonic function, regardless of linearity [28]. This finding suggests that population and the KL divergence tend to change together, but not necessarily at a constant rate. While we can identify a general scaling trend, our data also exhibit frequent outliers and deviations.
4. Discussion
Here, we proposed a new method to study the scaling of income distributions and income inequality in urban areas. The aggregated income in income deciles scales systematically with city size. The bottom decile scales with an exponent slightly below 1 and the top decile with an exponent of β = 1.15. This result suggests that the benefits of larger cities are increasingly unequally distributed, and for the poorest income deciles, cities have no positive effect over the null expectation of a linear increase. Much has been written about the apparent increasing gains of large cities [4,5], such as greater GDP, higher wages and more patents per capita. Our results show that the increasing benefits of city size are not evenly distributed to people within those cities. We further show systematic variations in distribution characteristics. Besides greater mean, distributions of bigger cities also exhibit greater spread, greater asymmetry and heavier tails. These perspectives can be explicitly connected to traditional measures of income inequality, such as the Gini coefficient. Like the Gini coefficient, our method characterizes the overall dispersion of income distributions (figure 7), but it also provides more detailed information that is not characterized by Gini, such as how the urban agglomeration effect alters the incomes of relatively poor or rich people differently.
Since income distribution data represent a sub-sample of the population, it is important to consider how sub-sampling may affect the scaling exponents [29]. We performed a robustness check and found that our conclusions are not affected by the sampling effect described in [29]—see electronic supplementary material for more details.
Our qualitative conclusions, at first glance, appear to closely align with those of Sarkar et al. [26,27], which analyse Australian income data. While both studies observe inequality, the two studies define inequality differently. Sarkar et al. uses a non-scale-adjusted method and study income aggregated in income brackets, while we use a scale-adjusted method and aggregate by income deciles. The baseline ‘equal’ situation is different in the two methods. In Sarkar et al., equality requires the proportion of individuals in each income bracket to remain the same as city size changes, and inequality can appear when the average income increases with city population, even without changes to the shape of the distribution. In our method, equality requires the dispersion in the income distribution to remain the same, regardless of changes in average income. Thus, our methodology allows us to distinguish between increasing income variance and increasing mean income, while Sarkar’s does not. Furthermore, the scale-adjusted approach is important when comparing income with other urban indicators, such as housing costs. Since the average of both variables scale with city population, and sometimes with different exponents, it is important to use the scale-adjusted approach to derive meaningful comparisons.
Our paper offers new contributions to the literature. First, we develop a new method to study income inequality in the urban scaling framework, which untangles the systematic shift in mean from the study of income inequality. This method enables us to study how income agglomeration effects vary between relatively rich and poor people, after accounting for the systematically increasing mean with population size. Second, our analysis including housing cost demonstrates that despite agglomeration effects on income, bigger cities are less affordable for people of all deciles in the sense that they spend proportionally more of their income on housing; this is especially true for lower-income people. Third, our analysis extends beyond the single-parameter characterization of income inequality. We analyse more complex properties of income distributions through analysing statistical moments and KL divergence, and reveal systematic variations with city size. Fourth, our results suggest new directions for understanding mechanisms of urban agglomeration effects—it is important to extend beyond theories considering homogeneous densifying interactions to those which account for heterogeneity.
Understanding the underlying mechanisms of why inequality is systematically scaling with city size is of great future interest with many potential implications. Urban scaling theory in general proposes densifying interactions within cities as the fundamental process leading to the superlinear increase of many features [3,9,10,30,31]. Our analysis shows that the superlinear scaling is not seen within all subsections of the city. The superlinear scaling of total wealth is driven by the top income deciles, and is not matched proportionally by the lowest deciles. This adds another dimension to considerations of the underlying mechanisms of urban scaling theory: what processes are leading to the increasingly unequal distribution of wealth in larger cities? We explored the idea of city heterogeneity as an indirect proxy for heterogeneous interaction rates. One hypothesis of the mechanism driving superlinear scaling of income with city size is that larger cities foster more and more diverse social and economic interactions, creating opportunities for the exchange of ideas and resources. Existing literature credits superlinear growth of income in cities to more opportunities for social contacts and interactions in large cities [4,9]. Increased social contact with city size has been empirically confirmed [32], and ties between individual’s exposure to diverse social connections and economic outcomes have been shown empirically as well [33]. Together, this seems to suggest that cities that are better mixed either physically or virtually, allowing diverse parts of the population to be exposed to one another, should be overperforming with respect to urban scaling. We hypothesize that cities with high levels of economic segregation, inhibiting mixing between diverse populations, will underperform with respect to income scaling. Our finding encourages future work to consider heterogeneous models of interactions, as those clustered in space or social/work circles, to form a more coherent understanding of urban scaling.
Data accessibility
Data can be accessed through the following repository: https://github.com/ElisaHeinrich/Inequality_Scaling. Income and housing cost data are from the 2015 American Community Survey, openly available through the United States Census Bureau https://www.census.gov/programs-surveys/acs.
Authors' contributions
C.E.H., C.P.K. and G.B.W. designed the initial study. E.H.M., V.C.Y., J.J. and C.P.K. designed an expansion of the initial study. E.H.M., J.J., V.C.Y., C.E.H. and C.P.K. performed both mathematical and data analyses. All authors wrote the manuscript.
Competing interests
We declare we have no competing interests.
Funding
C.P.K., G.B.W., C.E.H., E.H.M. and J.J. thank CAF Canada and Toby Shannan for generously supporting this work. J.J. was supported by an NSF REU (award no. 1757923) which also supported the publication of this paper. E.H.M. was supported by the ASU-SFI Center for Biosocial Complex Systems. V.C.Y. acknowledges support from the Omidyar fellowship, Suzanne Hurst and Samuel Peters. C.E.H. thanks the James Graham Brown Foundation and MIT Senseable City Lab. G.B.W. also thank the NSF for their generous support under the grant no. PHY1838420.
Acknowledgements
The authors thank Luis Bettencourt for useful discussions. C.H. thanks the MIT Senseable City Lab and all MIT Senseable City Consortium members for supporting this research. The authors thank Alyssa Johnson for useful input on the project.
References
- 1. United Nations. 2018 2018 Revision of world urbanization prospects. New York, NY: United Nations. Google Scholar
- 2.
Lobo J et al. 2020 Urban science: integrated theory from the first cities to sustainable metropolises. Report submitted to the NSF on the Present State and Future of Urban Science. See https://ssrn.com/abstract=3526940. Google Scholar - 3.
Pumain D, Paulus F, Vacchiani-Marcuzzo C, Lobo J . 2006 An evolutionary theory for interpreting urban scaling laws. Cybergeo: Eur. J. Geogr. document 343. (doi:10.4000/cybergeo.2519) Crossref, Google Scholar - 4.
Bettencourt LM, Lobo J, Helbing D, KÜhnert C, West GB . 2007 Growth, innovation, scaling, and the pace of life in cities. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 104, 7301-7306. (doi:10.1073/pnas.0610172104) Crossref, PubMed, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 5.
Bettencourt LM, Lobo J . 2016 Urban scaling in Europe. J. R. Soc. Interface 13, 20160005. (doi:10.1098/rsif.2016.0005) Link, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 6.
Meirelles J, Neto CR, Ferreira FF, Ribeiro FL, Binder CR . 2018 Evolution of urban scaling: evidence from Brazil. PLoS ONE 13, e0204574. (doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0204574) Crossref, PubMed, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 7.
Zünd D, Bettencourt LMA . 2019 Growth and development in prefecture-level cities in China. PLoS ONE 14, e0221017. (doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0221017) Crossref, PubMed, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 8.
Sahasranaman A, Bettencourt LMA . 2019 Urban geography and scaling of contemporary Indian cities. J. R. Soc. Interface 16, 20180758. (doi:10.1098/rsif.2018.0758) Link, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 9.
Bettencourt LM . 2013 The origins of scaling in cities. Science 340, 1438-1441. (doi:10.1126/science.1235823) Crossref, PubMed, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 10.
Yang VC, Papachristos AV, Abrams DM . 2019 Modeling the origin of urban-output scaling laws. Phys. Rev. E 100, 032306. (doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.100.032306) Crossref, PubMed, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 11.
Bowles S, Fong CM, Gintis H, Pagano U . 2012 The new economics of inequality and redistribution. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press. Crossref, Google Scholar - 12.
Piketty T . 2014 Capital in the 21st Century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Crossref, Google Scholar - 13.
Persson T, Tabellini G . 1991 Is inequality harmful for growth?: Theory and evindence. Cambridge, MA: Queen Elizabeth House. Crossref, Google Scholar - 14.
Alesina A, Rodrik D . 1994 Distributive politics and economic growth. Q. J. Econ. 109, 465-490. (doi:10.2307/2118470) Crossref, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 15.
Li H, Zou H-F . 1998 Income inequality is not harmful for growth: theory and evidence. Rev. Dev. Econ. 2, 318-334. (doi:10.1111/1467-9361.00045) Crossref, Google Scholar - 16.
Forbes KJ . 2000 A reassessment of the relationship between inequality and growth. Am. Econ. Rev. 90, 869-887. (doi:10.1257/aer.90.4.869) Crossref, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 17.
Barro RJ . 2000 Inequality and growth in a panel of countries. J. Econ. Growth 5, 5-32. (doi:10.1023/A:1009850119329) Crossref, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 18.
Pagano P . 2004 An empirical investigation of the relationship between inequality and growth. Economic working papers 536, Bank of Italy, Economic Research and International Relations Area. See https://ideas.repec.org/p/bdi/wptemi/td_536_04.html. Google Scholar - 19.
Alesina A, Perotti R . 1996 Income distribution, political instability, and investment. Eur. Econ. Rev. 40, 1203-1228. (doi:10.1016/0014-2921(95)00030-5) Crossref, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 20.
Kelly M . 2000 Inequality and crime. Rev. Econ. Stat. 82, 530-539. (doi:10.1162/003465300559028) Crossref, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 21.
Jong-Sung Y, Khagram S . 2005 A comparative study of inequality and corruption. Am. Sociol. Rev. 70, 136-157. (doi:10.1177/000312240507000107) Crossref, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 22.
Glaeser EL, Resseger M, Tobio K . 2009 Inequality in cities. J. Reg. Sci. 49, 617-646. (doi:10.1111/j.1467-9787.2009.00627.x) Crossref, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 23.
Behrens K, Nicoud FR . 2014 Survival of the fittest in cities: urbanisation and inequality. Econ. J. 124, 1371-1400. (doi:10.1111/ecoj.12099) Crossref, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 24.
Cottineau C, Finance O, Hatna E, Arcaute E, Batty M . 2019 Defining urban clusters to detect agglomeration economies. Environ. Plann. B: Urban Anal. City Sci. 46, 1611-1626. (doi:10.1177/2399808318755146) Crossref, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 25.
Snow NB, Pavan R . 2013 Inequality and city size. Rev. Econ. Stat. 95, 1535-1548. (doi:10.1162/REST_a_00328) Crossref, PubMed, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 26.
Sarkar S, Phibbs P, Simpson R, Wasnik S . 2018 The scaling of income distribution in Australia: possible relationships between urban allometry, city size, and economic inequality. Environ. Plann. B: Urban Anal. City Sci. 45, 603-622. (doi:10.1177/0265813516676488) Crossref, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 27.
Sarkar S . 2019 Urban scaling and the geographic concentration of inequalities by city size. Environ. Plann. B: Urban Anal. City Sci. 46, 1627-1644. (doi:10.1177/2399808318766070) Crossref, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 28.
Salkind N . 2007 Encyclopedia of measurement and statistics. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE. Crossref, Google Scholar - 29.
Gómez-Liévano A, Vysotsky V, Lobo J . 2021 Artificial increasing returns to scale and the problem of sampling from lognormals. Environ. Plann. B: Urban Anal. City Sci. 48, 1574-1590. (doi:10.1177/2399808320942366) Crossref, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 30.
Gomez-Lievano A, Patterson-Lomba O, Hausmann R . 2016 Explaining the prevalence, scaling and variance of urban phenomena. Nat. Human Behav. 1, 1-6. (doi:10.1038/s41562-016-0012) Web of Science, Google Scholar - 31.
Pan W, Ghoshal G, Krumme C, Cebrian M, Pentland A . 2013 Urban characteristics attributable to density-driven tie formation. Nat. Commun. 4, 1-7. (doi:10.1038/ncomms2961) Crossref, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 32.
Schläpfer M, Bettencourt LM, Grauwin S, Raschke M, Claxton R, Smoreda Z, West GB, Ratti C . 2014 The scaling of human interactions with city size. J. R. Soc. Interface 11, 20130789. (doi:10.1098/rsif.2013.0789) Link, Web of Science, Google Scholar - 33.
Chetty R, Hendren N . 2018 The impacts of neighborhoods on intergenerational mobility I: childhood exposure effects. Q. J. Econ. 133, 1107-1162. (doi:10.1093/qje/qjy007) Crossref, Web of Science, Google Scholar